Click the button to display the subtitles next to the video.

Loading...

Tenses

English Subtitles

0: Hi I'm Adriene Hill and I'm Jacob Clifford and welcome to Crash Course Economics.

4: Today we're going to talk about international trade. So we all know our stuff is from everywhere.

10: Bangladesh, China, Vietnam, China again,

13: but what does it actually tell us about the global economy or the US economy?

17: And who's is benefitting from all this trade. And who's gonna clean all this up?

20: [Theme Music]

29: International trade is the lifeblood of the global economy. Basically when a good

33: or service is produced in, let's say, Brazil and sold to a person or business in the

37: US, that counts as an export for Brazil and as an import from US. As you might

41: expect, the United States is the world's largest importer because Americans love

45: their stuff. In 2014 Americans imported over two trillion dollars worth of stuff,

50: like oil, cars and clothing from countries all over the world. And if you

53: look around your local big box store, it feels like everything is made in China.

57: And we do import a lot of things from China but in terms of both imports, and

61: exports our largest trading partner's not China, it's Canada. The US and Canada trade

66: over six hundred billion dollars worth of goods and services each year.

69: The US imports a lot from Canada but exports almost as much. In fact, the United States is

73: the world's second-largest exporter. It sells high-tech things like

76: pharmaceuticals, jet turbines, generators and aircraft to countries all over the world.

81: It also exports intellectual goods like Kanye West albums and Pixar movies as

84: well as bulk commodities like corn, oil and cotton. The annual difference between

88: a country's exports and imports is called net exports. So if Brazil exports 250

93: billion dollars worth of goods and imports 200 billion that its net exports

98: are fifty billion. That means Brazil has a trade surplus. In 2014, net exports in

103: the US were negative 722 billion dollars. That's what you call a trade deficit.

108: Some people assume that having a trade deficit is inherently bad. Why does the

112: US import nearly all of its clothing? Why can't we clothe ourselves?

116: US producers could easily make more than enough clothing to keep all of us

120: dressed. But they don't because they focus on other things that they're better at

124: producing. The US buys clothes from other countries because we can get them

128: cheaper than if we made them here. This is the value of international trade. It

133: doesn't make sense to make everything on your own if you can trade with other

136: countries that have a comparative advantage. It's worth mentioning here

140: that these savings sometimes come with other costs, especially for the people

145: who are producing these goods overseas. Unsafe and unfair working conditions, and

150: environmental degradation can be ugly side effects of

154: international trade. And we're gonna talk about that. For today though let's get a handle

159: on trade deficits. It can seem like exporting would make a country wealthy

163: while importing would make it poor. After all, if we buy products produced in other

167: countries then we're shipping jobs overseas, right? Well only to an extent.

172: Imagine that I have a choice of buying an American made TV or a TV made in

177: Malaysia. Because of lower labor costs in Malaysia the imported TV cost $200 less

183: than the American made one. So I buy the imported TV. That may cost jobs at a TV

188: factory in the US but I saved $200 by buying the imported TV. And what am I

194: gonna do with those $200? I'm gonna spend them on something I couldn't have

197: afforded if I bought the US TV. Like maybe taking my family out to a baseball game

201: or to a restaurant. That creates jobs in those industries that wouldn't have

205: existed if I'd bought the more expensive TV. Economic theory suggests that

209: international trade reshuffles jobs from one sector of the economy to another, like

214: from the TV factory to the restaurant. But the quality of these jobs can be

218: markedly different. The guy assembling TVs at the US factory was probably

223: making a lot more at his manufacturing job before he got reshuffled to the burrito

228: assembly line at Chipotle. Which is just to say all this is really complicated

233: and what is good in the aggregate is not necessarily good for individuals. For

237: example, look at the North American Free Trade Agreement or NAFTA. It was

241: established in 1994 to drop trade barriers between Canada, the United

245: States and Mexico. Critics point out that NAFTA significantly increased US trade

251: deficits and they say it decreased the number of manufacturing jobs in many

256: states, as companies moved out of the US. Proponents of free trade point out that

260: the US economy boomed in the 1990's, creating millions of jobs including manufacturing jobs, and that free trade

268: has decreased the prices of all sorts of consumer goods, from vegetables to cars. So despite the fact

273: that some workers and industries were clearly hurt, economist would tell us

278: NAFTA's had a net positive impact on all three countries. By the way, you know

283: Thought café, the makers of the Thought Bubble? They're Canadian. These

287: graphics are imported. The debate over the value of specific trade agreements

291: continues. But it's unlikely that the world's largest economies will return to

296: strict protectionism. Protectionist policy, like placing high tariffs on

300: imports and limiting the number of foreign goods, usually hurts an economy

304: more than it helps. There are now several organizations designed to eradicate

309: protectionism, most notably the World Trade Organization or WTO. The WTO has been

315: effective in getting countries to agree to specific rules and help settle

319: disputes, but it's also been accused of favouring rich countries and not doing

323: enough to protect the environment or workers. Trade between countries depends

327: on the demand for a country's goods, political stability and interest rates,

331: but one of the most important factors is exchange rates. Basically this is how

336: much your currency is worth when you trade it for another country's currency.

339: And let's engage in some foreign trade now by going to the Thought Bubble. Suppose the

344: US-Mexico exchange rate is 15 pesos to the dollar. If an American's on vacation in Mexico and wants to

350: buy some sunscreen that cost 60 pesos, they'll have to trade four dollars for pesos. Likewise if someone from

357: Mexico is on vacation in the US and wants to buy a $20 t-shirt she will need to exchange 300 pesos for

363: dollars. Now one let's think about what happens if the exchange rate goes up to twenty

368: pesos per dollar. Now to buy that 50 peso sunscreen in mexico it'll cost the American

372: tourist $3 instead of four. We say that the dollar has appreciated. At the same

378: time the Mexican tourist who wants to buy the $20 t-shirt will need four

382: hundred pesos instead of 300. It works the same way with imports and exports.

386: When the dollar appreciates, it gets cheaper for US consumers to import

391: foreign goods, and US exports to other countries get more expensive. US imports

397: rise and export fall. On the other hand

400: what if the exchange rate fell to 10 pesos per dollar? Now to buy that

404: sunscreen, the american tourist needs $6. Each dollar has gotten less powerful. We

409: say that the dollar has depreciated. At the same time, the Mexican tourist who

413: wants to buy the $20 t-shirt needs only two hundred pesos. So when the dollar

418: depreciates, foreign imports get more expensive which means they fall, and US

423: exports to other countries get cheaper which means they rise.

426: Most currencies, like the peso and the dollar have floating exchange rates that

430: change based on supply and demand. Like when the US imports more products from

433: Mexico, they exchange dollars for pesos. This will increase the demand for pesos,

437: and the peso will appreciate. At the same time, the dollar will depreciate. Now some

442: countries have elected to peg their currency to another currency. This is

445: when a country's central bank wants to keep the exchange rate in a certain

448: range, and they buy or sell currencies to keep it in that range. The Chinese

452: government was well known for buying US dollars to keep the Chinese currency

455: artificially depreciated. When the US is importing goods from China, the yuan

459: would appreciate. Then the Chinese government would turn around and buy

462: dollars which kept the exchange rate about the same. This kept Chinese exports

466: cheap for Americans. Up to this point, we focused on exporting and importing goods

469: and services but there's a whole other side of international trade that involves

473: financial assets. Let's look at something called the balance of payments. It might

476: feel more like accounting than economics, but it helps to show how flows of money and

480: flows of goods and services are opposite sides of the same coin. Every country

483: keeps an accounting statement called the balance of payments that records all

487: international transactions. It's made up of two sub-accounts, the current account

490: and the financial account, sometimes called the capital account. The current

493: account records the sale and purchase of goods and services, investment income

497: earned abroad, and other transfers like donations and foreign aid. So when the US buys

501: fifty billion dollars of computers from China, that's recorded in the US current

505: account. So this is a simplification, but when Americans spend money on Chinese

508: goods, the people in China, in theory, have only two things they can do with that

512: money. They can buy US goods, or they can buy US financial assets, like stocks and

516: bonds. These transactions are recorded in the other side of account, the financial

519: account. There is a reason why the flow of goods and the flow of money are

522: symmetric. If consumers, businesses, and government want to buy more stuff than their

527: country is producing domestically, they have to import it. So there's a trade deficit. That country has to sell

532: assets to pay for those imports, and that's recorded in the financial account. The United

536: States has a very low savings rate which means it's consuming everything it's

539: producing and it sells assets to pay for the additional output it brings in from

543: overseas. Americans are choosing to run a trade deficit. International trade, like

547: everything else in economics, is about trade-offs and choices and winners and

551: losers. In purely economic terms trade deficits and surpluses are the result of

556: people and nations seeking their own self-interests. But while everyone is

560: acting in the self-interested way, international trade doesn't always meet

564: our individual interests. What might be good for the wider global economy, might

569: be really bad for me or my hometown. But in the aggregate, trade does improve the

575: global standard of living. It's just sometimes hard to see up close. Thanks for watching, we'll see you next week.

582: Crash Course Economics was made with the help of all these nice people. You can support

586: Crash Course at Patreon, where you can help keep Crash Course

589: free for everyone, forever. And you get rewards. Thanks for watching, DFTBA.

Introduction

How imports and exports affect exchange rates.

Dictionary definitions

Click on the word or phrase to search the dictionary.

In other videos

Click on the words to search our database of videos.

The full text

0: Hi I'm Adriene Hill and I'm Jacob Clifford and welcome to Crash Course Economics.
4: Today we're going to talk about international trade. So we all know our stuff is from everywhere.
10: Bangladesh, China, Vietnam, China again,
13: but what does it actually tell us about the global economy or the US economy?
17: And who's is benefitting from all this trade. And who's gonna clean all this up?
20: [Theme Music]
29: International trade is the lifeblood of the global economy. Basically when a good
33: or service is produced in, let's say, Brazil and sold to a person or business in the
37: US, that counts as an export for Brazil and as an import from US. As you might
41: expect, the United States is the world's largest importer because Americans love
45: their stuff. In 2014 Americans imported over two trillion dollars worth of stuff,
50: like oil, cars and clothing from countries all over the world. And if you
53: look around your local big box store, it feels like everything is made in China.
57: And we do import a lot of things from China but in terms of both imports, and
61: exports our largest trading partner's not China, it's Canada. The US and Canada trade
66: over six hundred billion dollars worth of goods and services each year.
69: The US imports a lot from Canada but exports almost as much. In fact, the United States is
73: the world's second-largest exporter. It sells high-tech things like
76: pharmaceuticals, jet turbines, generators and aircraft to countries all over the world.
81: It also exports intellectual goods like Kanye West albums and Pixar movies as
84: well as bulk commodities like corn, oil and cotton. The annual difference between
88: a country's exports and imports is called net exports. So if Brazil exports 250
93: billion dollars worth of goods and imports 200 billion that its net exports
98: are fifty billion. That means Brazil has a trade surplus. In 2014, net exports in
103: the US were negative 722 billion dollars. That's what you call a trade deficit.
108: Some people assume that having a trade deficit is inherently bad. Why does the
112: US import nearly all of its clothing? Why can't we clothe ourselves?
116: US producers could easily make more than enough clothing to keep all of us
120: dressed. But they don't because they focus on other things that they're better at
124: producing. The US buys clothes from other countries because we can get them
128: cheaper than if we made them here. This is the value of international trade. It
133: doesn't make sense to make everything on your own if you can trade with other
136: countries that have a comparative advantage. It's worth mentioning here
140: that these savings sometimes come with other costs, especially for the people
145: who are producing these goods overseas. Unsafe and unfair working conditions, and
150: environmental degradation can be ugly side effects of
154: international trade. And we're gonna talk about that. For today though let's get a handle
159: on trade deficits. It can seem like exporting would make a country wealthy
163: while importing would make it poor. After all, if we buy products produced in other
167: countries then we're shipping jobs overseas, right? Well only to an extent.
172: Imagine that I have a choice of buying an American made TV or a TV made in
177: Malaysia. Because of lower labor costs in Malaysia the imported TV cost $200 less
183: than the American made one. So I buy the imported TV. That may cost jobs at a TV
188: factory in the US but I saved $200 by buying the imported TV. And what am I
194: gonna do with those $200? I'm gonna spend them on something I couldn't have
197: afforded if I bought the US TV. Like maybe taking my family out to a baseball game
201: or to a restaurant. That creates jobs in those industries that wouldn't have
205: existed if I'd bought the more expensive TV. Economic theory suggests that
209: international trade reshuffles jobs from one sector of the economy to another, like
214: from the TV factory to the restaurant. But the quality of these jobs can be
218: markedly different. The guy assembling TVs at the US factory was probably
223: making a lot more at his manufacturing job before he got reshuffled to the burrito
228: assembly line at Chipotle. Which is just to say all this is really complicated
233: and what is good in the aggregate is not necessarily good for individuals. For
237: example, look at the North American Free Trade Agreement or NAFTA. It was
241: established in 1994 to drop trade barriers between Canada, the United
245: States and Mexico. Critics point out that NAFTA significantly increased US trade
251: deficits and they say it decreased the number of manufacturing jobs in many
256: states, as companies moved out of the US. Proponents of free trade point out that
260: the US economy boomed in the 1990's, creating millions of jobs including manufacturing jobs, and that free trade
268: has decreased the prices of all sorts of consumer goods, from vegetables to cars. So despite the fact
273: that some workers and industries were clearly hurt, economist would tell us
278: NAFTA's had a net positive impact on all three countries. By the way, you know
283: Thought café, the makers of the Thought Bubble? They're Canadian. These
287: graphics are imported. The debate over the value of specific trade agreements
291: continues. But it's unlikely that the world's largest economies will return to
296: strict protectionism. Protectionist policy, like placing high tariffs on
300: imports and limiting the number of foreign goods, usually hurts an economy
304: more than it helps. There are now several organizations designed to eradicate
309: protectionism, most notably the World Trade Organization or WTO. The WTO has been
315: effective in getting countries to agree to specific rules and help settle
319: disputes, but it's also been accused of favouring rich countries and not doing
323: enough to protect the environment or workers. Trade between countries depends
327: on the demand for a country's goods, political stability and interest rates,
331: but one of the most important factors is exchange rates. Basically this is how
336: much your currency is worth when you trade it for another country's currency.
339: And let's engage in some foreign trade now by going to the Thought Bubble. Suppose the
344: US-Mexico exchange rate is 15 pesos to the dollar. If an American's on vacation in Mexico and wants to
350: buy some sunscreen that cost 60 pesos, they'll have to trade four dollars for pesos. Likewise if someone from
357: Mexico is on vacation in the US and wants to buy a $20 t-shirt she will need to exchange 300 pesos for
363: dollars. Now one let's think about what happens if the exchange rate goes up to twenty
368: pesos per dollar. Now to buy that 50 peso sunscreen in mexico it'll cost the American
372: tourist $3 instead of four. We say that the dollar has appreciated. At the same
378: time the Mexican tourist who wants to buy the $20 t-shirt will need four
382: hundred pesos instead of 300. It works the same way with imports and exports.
386: When the dollar appreciates, it gets cheaper for US consumers to import
391: foreign goods, and US exports to other countries get more expensive. US imports
397: rise and export fall. On the other hand
400: what if the exchange rate fell to 10 pesos per dollar? Now to buy that
404: sunscreen, the american tourist needs $6. Each dollar has gotten less powerful. We
409: say that the dollar has depreciated. At the same time, the Mexican tourist who
413: wants to buy the $20 t-shirt needs only two hundred pesos. So when the dollar
418: depreciates, foreign imports get more expensive which means they fall, and US
423: exports to other countries get cheaper which means they rise.
426: Most currencies, like the peso and the dollar have floating exchange rates that
430: change based on supply and demand. Like when the US imports more products from
433: Mexico, they exchange dollars for pesos. This will increase the demand for pesos,
437: and the peso will appreciate. At the same time, the dollar will depreciate. Now some
442: countries have elected to peg their currency to another currency. This is
445: when a country's central bank wants to keep the exchange rate in a certain
448: range, and they buy or sell currencies to keep it in that range. The Chinese
452: government was well known for buying US dollars to keep the Chinese currency
455: artificially depreciated. When the US is importing goods from China, the yuan
459: would appreciate. Then the Chinese government would turn around and buy
462: dollars which kept the exchange rate about the same. This kept Chinese exports
466: cheap for Americans. Up to this point, we focused on exporting and importing goods
469: and services but there's a whole other side of international trade that involves
473: financial assets. Let's look at something called the balance of payments. It might
476: feel more like accounting than economics, but it helps to show how flows of money and
480: flows of goods and services are opposite sides of the same coin. Every country
483: keeps an accounting statement called the balance of payments that records all
487: international transactions. It's made up of two sub-accounts, the current account
490: and the financial account, sometimes called the capital account. The current
493: account records the sale and purchase of goods and services, investment income
497: earned abroad, and other transfers like donations and foreign aid. So when the US buys
501: fifty billion dollars of computers from China, that's recorded in the US current
505: account. So this is a simplification, but when Americans spend money on Chinese
508: goods, the people in China, in theory, have only two things they can do with that
512: money. They can buy US goods, or they can buy US financial assets, like stocks and
516: bonds. These transactions are recorded in the other side of account, the financial
519: account. There is a reason why the flow of goods and the flow of money are
522: symmetric. If consumers, businesses, and government want to buy more stuff than their
527: country is producing domestically, they have to import it. So there's a trade deficit. That country has to sell
532: assets to pay for those imports, and that's recorded in the financial account. The United
536: States has a very low savings rate which means it's consuming everything it's
539: producing and it sells assets to pay for the additional output it brings in from
543: overseas. Americans are choosing to run a trade deficit. International trade, like
547: everything else in economics, is about trade-offs and choices and winners and
551: losers. In purely economic terms trade deficits and surpluses are the result of
556: people and nations seeking their own self-interests. But while everyone is
560: acting in the self-interested way, international trade doesn't always meet
564: our individual interests. What might be good for the wider global economy, might
569: be really bad for me or my hometown. But in the aggregate, trade does improve the
575: global standard of living. It's just sometimes hard to see up close. Thanks for watching, we'll see you next week.
582: Crash Course Economics was made with the help of all these nice people. You can support
586: Crash Course at Patreon, where you can help keep Crash Course
589: free for everyone, forever. And you get rewards. Thanks for watching, DFTBA.

Save words

Click on the word or phrase to save to your account.

Business English 23 User Centre

user

Register with Business English 23 to save words and phrases: Login

Channel Information
CrashCourse

We really like the videos from Crash Course! An American YouTube channel, Crash Course produces high-quality educational videos to help you get better grades at your college or university. These videos look at subjects related to economics and the financial markets, so if you are studying economics at University you really should check out this channel. You should be able to understand the videos if you have upper-intermediate level English. Get better grades in your economics course thanks to Crash Course!

Subscribe to this Youtube channel